(Note: Now this article has been published at Indian Defence Review and can also be accessed HERE)
Winning the Asymmetric Wars – A need for Rapid Strategic Switching
Winning the Asymmetric Wars – A need for Rapid Strategic Switching
Of
the 43 asymmetric wars in the period 1950-1999, 51.2% wars have been won by the
weaker actor. That the powerful will lose sometimes is in the nature of warfare,
in general. However, they will lose in more than 50% of the times is difficult
to explain especially in the established way of creating powerful military
forces by nations with large populations and high economic resources. Ivan
Arreguin-Toft, in his 2005 book, “How the weak win wars – a theory of asymmetric conflict”, analyses the data of asymmetric conflicts in the 200 years’
period from 1800 to 2003 and comes up with this startling trend of David’s have
started winning more often than the Goliaths. The overall win percentage, sure
enough, is still in favour of stronger, more powerful actors – they winning
71.5% of times. However, when he presents the data in 50-year time slots – the trend
becomes increasingly stark and surprising. Consider
this, for example, for the 34 asymmetrical conflicts from the year 1800 to
1849, the winning % of strong actors was 88.2%. For the period from 1850 to
1899 it reduced to 79.5% for 78 such conflicts that occurred in that
half-century. For the first 50 years of 20th century, the world
witnesses 43 asymmetrical conflicts, in those, the winning percentage of strong
actors reduced to 65.1%.
Explanation of continuing
Victories of David’s
Relative
combat power as a measure of win probability has been an established norm in
the studies on military combat between state actors, in general. Also, use of innovative weapons as for example
the use of a catapult by David against Goliath, in the biblical story, has been
considered as one possible explanation of success of weaker actors in the
asymmetrical conflicts. Besides these, nature of strong actor – whether a democracy
or an authoritarian regime or dictator has also been considered to explain the
relative success of dictators in such conflicts. Arms diffusion – when the
weaker gets the modern arms specially after WWII – when many developing world
countries received modern weapons and used them against stronger attackers,
have also been offered as an explanation of some wins by the weaker actors.
Toft,
however, presents a neat hypothesis of what he calls Strategic
Interaction of opposing actors approaches in the asymmetric conflicts.
He divides all war strategies into two main categories – Direct strategies and Indirect
strategies. Direct strategies are those that are typically executed by
military forces against the opponent military forces only with the aim to
destroy opponents physical/infrastructural capability to fight wars. In fact,
these are typically what one considers when looking at an actor’s combat
potential. These pure military strategies do not, per se, target non-combatants
on both sides. The Indirect strategies, however, target the enemy’s will to
fight. Typically, focusing on destroying the support systems in the form of
non-combatants or the population at large. Toft includes in indirect strategies
Barbarism – systematic/deliberate attack/harm of non-combatants by the strong
actor and Guerrilla Warfare Strategy (GWS) by the weak actor. The Strategic Interaction hypothesis for
asymmetric wars is when the opponents opt for same-approach, i.e.,
direct-direct or indirect-indirect strategic interactions, the strong actor will
win, if however, the approaches are different that is one actor opts for direct
strategy and other an indirect strategy – the weaker actor will win.
Strategic Interaction
The key point of Strategic Interaction
hypothesis is that every strategy has an ideal counter-strategy. Predicting
adversary’s strategy in advance can dramatically improve chances of victory. To
test this strategic interaction hypothesis, Toft analyzed the asymmetric conflicts
data of 173 wars between year 1800 and 2003. As per the results of this
exercise, in 151 conflicts opponents used “same-approach” i.e., either
direct-direct or indirect-indirect. Out of these 151 conflicts 76.8% of the
conflicts – the stronger actor was the winner. In 22 remaining asymmetric
conflicts when “different-approach” was used, i.e., one actor using direct and
other using indirect strategies, 63.6% of the times the weaker actor won the
conflict. Toft’s strategic interaction model as shown in 2x2 matrix in the
figure, also shows that strong actors will more often lose asymmetric conflicts
that are protracted.
Inability to switch
strategy
Toft
finds that in 78% of asymmetric conflicts the losing actors did not switch
strategy. Actors with force structures, doctrines, and technologies, that have
been created, developed, trained and honed, typically for “symmetric” conflicts
and “same-approach” scenarios, find it difficult to change their strategies.
This strategic inertia becomes the key
culprit in the trends of strong powerful actors increasingly losing to weaker
actors in the asymmetric wars. The impedance mismatch between the shift in
nature of threats versus the speed at which an actor can shift strategy emerges
in asymmetric conflicts is one of the factors that should be considered while
planning for next conflicts. Designing malleable force structures with fungible
components is the key need.
Lessons for India
India
has been subjected to asymmetric warfare by Pakistan after 1971 creation of
Bangladesh. Bhutto promised a 1000-year war and Zia-ul-Haq talked about
bleeding by 1000 cuts. After the overt nuclear status in 1998, Pakistan’s
Military again lost in 1999 Kargil war. As India celebrated the 17th
anniversary of Vijay Diwas – to mark our victory in Kargil war of 1999, there
are much larger questions on Indian security, defence preparedness and military
readiness that need to be answered. K Subrahmanyam chaired Kargil review committee was constituted to
review the events leading up to the Pakistani aggression in the Kargil and to
recommend such measures as are considered necessary to safeguard national
security against such armed intrusions. The most important finding of the
review committee was “overwhelming evidence that the Pakistani armed intrusion
in the Kargil sector came as a complete
and total surprise to the Indian Government, Army and intelligence agencies
as well as to the J&K State Government and its agencies.” As we battle the
current reactions in Kashmir after the elimination of a terrorist leader, we
need to answer the Kargil question of how to minimize the “complete and total
surprise” and also create a capability or set of capabilities to make “strategy
shifts” not only do-able but to be done in a seamless manner.
“Modern war has too wide an effect for its
practice to be treated as a “mystery." Statesmen may direct it; generals,
admirals and air marshals may manage its operations but every citizen, man or
woman, is perforce a shareholder.” Captain
Liddell Hart wrote in 1930s. He further stated, on the way peace time exercises
are carried out that, “The unreality is
often increased because the situations on which exercises are based have
themselves an air of improbability. This is due largely to a tendency, natural
in those who are practicing any particular technique, to, think of war in bits
instead of as a whole. They find it difficult to visualize the effect on
their bit that others may produce, with the result that the picture is
distorted.” He asserts, “The best corrective
to the particularistic tendency is to view each aspect of war against a wider
background.”
Liddell
Hart’s articulation of “indirect approach” of mechanized/armored warfare was utilized,
not by British, but the Germans in the form of combining Panzer divisions with
the aircraft, in Second World War. The above statements were published during
the period between World War I and World War II.
If
in 1930’s, the “best corrective” of thinking of war “in bits” instead of as a
“whole”, was to view each aspect of war against a wider background, the question emerges what one should do in
2010’s to view “war as a whole”. The bits of war, for example, have
expanded in 2010s in more dimensions than were fathomed in 1930s. The question
assumes increasing importance for a country like India that has many parameters
of a great nation. The problem is a woeful shortage of evidence of deeper
understanding of changing nature of warfare and needed innovation in
security/defence in India. Being on the receiving end of worst level of
asymmetric warfare/terrorism at one level, and sandwiched between two cunning
nuclear powers, i.e. Pakistan and China, India perhaps need a much deeper
thinking and design of its force structures for strategic switching.
Rapid Strategic Switching
– A recipe for winning Asymmetrical Conflict
What
future reveals is such a varied tapestry of possibilities that there cannot be
any expert and of course no opinion as well, beforehand, that can predict it,
Nostradamus notwithstanding. Yet, many have tried, although with limited
success to predict the future. In fact, all long term planning is based on a
picture or a presumed collage of future. However, one trend is quite visible –
that conflicts inflicted upon India will be more and more asymmetric –
typically instigated by covert support by adversary states to achieve
political, strategic, and economic objectives through the indirect or direct instigation
of insurgency. The type of conflicts that India will continue to face and most
likely with increasing frequency, distribution in space and time, and
increasing intensity will be asymmetrical. The state adversaries of India –
including China, Pakistan and others, will keep on finding surrogates/intermediaries
who can be influenced, financed and supported to unleash asymmetrical conflicts
as weaker actors. India of course need to go after their sponsors. However, we
also need to face their intermediaries with agility and create winnable
strategies in these asymmetrical conflicts
Overcoming
strategic inertia in any conflict and using Toft’s strategic interaction
hypothesis will require three key steps. First
we need to predict, deduce, define, and delineate the adversary’s strategy in
the asymmetric conflict. Second we
need to create same strategic interaction, i.e., if the weaker adversary is
following an indirect approach we need to follow an indirect strategy. If the
adversary follows direct approach, we need to follow a direct approach. Third when the opponent switches it
strategy – say from indirect to the direct, we should also switch from indirect
approach to direct approach. I call this three-step process as Rapid Strategic Switching (RSS).
Robert
Axelrod did extensive experiments on what is called iterated prisoners dilemma
in game theory. His results show the best strategy that ultimately evolves
cooperation is Tit for Tat. If the adversary cooperates you cooperate, if he
defects you also defect. Combining the Rapid Strategic Switching with Tit for
Tat, we should keep on switching strategies in tune with the deduced switches
in his strategy, till the adversary’s resources and bandwidth are exhausted or
his will to continue the conflict is demolished.
A
graduated response evolution targeting the starting seeds of threats to nations
interest should be our algorithm. Unfortunately, India does not articulate
national interests clearly and hence we remain woefully reactive and world cast
a continuous slur on India. We are being nibbled away by all. Rapid Strategic Switching
is not about being violent. It is about disruption, degradation, destruction
and most importantly demolition of all those actions or potential actions that
threaten our justified national interests. When you demolish you systematically
eliminate existing infrastructure with the intent of freeing the space to
install something different and hopefully something better. Every action starts
with a thought. Some of these thoughts become ideas that get manifested in
multiple ways. Conducting Rapid Strategic Switching at the level of strategic
interaction in asymmetrical conflicts require continuous evolution at the level
of ideas and actions simultaneously.
Conclusions
An
analysis of past 200 years reveals a counter-intuitive trend that the weaker
actors in asymmetric conflicts have started winning more than the powerful
actors. Statistical analysis reveals that strategic interaction hypothesis that
dissimilarity of strategies adopted by adversaries lead to victory of weaker
actors, holds good. Further, it has been pointed out that stronger actors as
they have designed their forces and capabilities based on specific threats, are
usually not free to choose the best counter-action strategy in these conflicts.
A force structure, doctrine and technology that enables quickly shifting the
approach in resonance with the weaker actor’s approach is the key requirement.
We propose the rapid strategic switching with three steps of predicting or
finding adversary’s strategy, responding by creating the same-type approach and
rapidly switching to the type the adversary shifts should be a continuous
tit-for-tat strategic approach to win the asymmetric wars.